Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
B. Frey, A. Stutzer (2001)
What Can Economists Learn from Happiness Research?Experimental & Empirical Studies eJournal
R. Benedict (2019)
Patterns of CultureNature, 136
D. Kahneman, J. Knetsch, R. Thaler (2004)
CHAPTER EIGHT. Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking: Entitlements in the Market
G. Marwell, Ruth Ames (1981)
Economists free ride, does anyone else? : Experiments on the provision of public goods, IVJournal of Public Economics, 15
G. Stigler (1948)
The Theory of Price
R. Chessick (1980)
Psychotherapy and the Human PredicamentAmerican Journal of Psychotherapy, 34
D. Hamermesh, Neal Soss (1974)
An Economic Theory of SuicideJournal of Political Economy, 82
James Wilson (1993)
The Moral SenseAmerican Political Science Review, 87
S. Milgram (1963)
BEHAVIORAL STUDY OF OBEDIENCE.Journal of abnormal psychology, 67
P. Cushman (1990)
Why the self is empty. Toward a historically situated psychology.The American psychologist, 45 5
S. O'Donohoe, Adam Ferrier (2012)
Thinking, Fast and SlowInternational Journal of Advertising, 31
J. Andreoni (1990)
IMPURE ALTRUISM AND DONATIONS TO PUBLIC GOODS: A THEORY OF WARM-GLOW GIVING*The Economic Journal, 100
J. McGinnis (2011)
The Young and Restless: Generation Y in the Nonprofit WorkforcePublic Administration Quarterly, 35
C. Haney, Curtis Banks, P. Zimbardo (1972)
Interpersonal Dynamics in a Simulated Prison
Hendrik Jürges (2001)
Do Germans Save to Leave an Estate? An Examination of the Bequest MotiveThe Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 103
Corry Azzi, Ronald Ehrenberg (1975)
Household Allocation of Time and Church AttendanceJournal of Political Economy, 83
R. Tella, Robert MacCulloch, A. Oswald (2001)
The Macroeconomics of HappinessReview of Economics and Statistics, 85
[Each branch of social science bears within it an implicit characterization of human nature. To an economist, humans are self-interest maximizers; to a behavioral economist, they are hopelessly irrational; to an anthropologist, they are products of a cultural time and place; to a sociologist, they are units in broad social webs and power structures; and so on. Each discipline makes a contribution to the aggregated conception of what constitutes human nature, but none can convincingly account for humans as “moral wrestlers,” as creatures that are concerned about themselves as well as questions of right versus wrong. Historically, the world’s major religions have carried the torch for man’s moral nature. Since the Enlightenment project has not sent religion off into obsolescence as promised, the practitioners of human-based sciences can still today learn from the religious conception of humans as moral wrestlers. This chapter calls on social scientists to break with their disciplines’ consensuses and refocus their image of human nature.]
Published: Jan 9, 2018
Read and print from thousands of top scholarly journals.
Already have an account? Log in
Bookmark this article. You can see your Bookmarks on your DeepDyve Library.
To save an article, log in first, or sign up for a DeepDyve account if you don’t already have one.
Copy and paste the desired citation format or use the link below to download a file formatted for EndNote
Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
All DeepDyve websites use cookies to improve your online experience. They were placed on your computer when you launched this website. You can change your cookie settings through your browser.