Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
(2011)
Comparison of China, Japan and Korea’s economic development approaches and its
(2004)
The political management of state - led industrial adjustment : The Japanese and French cases during the period of high economic growth
(2020)
A study on the change of family welfare policy in Korea in the context of low fertility crisis
Andrew Wedeman (1997)
Lootcers, Rent-Scrapers, and Dividend-ollectors: Corruption and Growth in Zaire, South Korea, and the PhilippinesJournal of Developing Areas, 31
(1997)
The current situation of women’s social status and its causes in Taiwan
(2016)
The historical evolution and inspiration of Korea’s foreign economic strategy
(2006)
A comparative study of labor relations management in the United States
(1999)
Causes and treatment of unemployment problems in China and Korea
(1996)
Human resource management and development in Korean companies
Eiji Yamamura, Inyong Shin, Hyunho Kim (2008)
The Cubic Form Hypothesis and the Flying Geese Pattern Hypothesis of Income Distribution: The Case of KoreaTheoretical and Empirical Researches in Urban Management, 7
H Koo (1984)
The political economy of income distribution in South Korea: The impact of the state’s industrialization policiesWorld Development, 12
(2000)
Korea’s technological innovation strategy and the impact on its economic recovery
M. Shizume, Masatoshi Kato, R. Matsuda (2021)
A corporate-centred conservative welfare regime: three-layered protection in JapanJournal of Asian Public Policy, 14
(2012)
Japan ’ s experience of industrial development to promote vocational education and its lessons
(2011)
The key orientation of the construction of China ’ s unemployment protection system – Taking Japan ’ s experience in combating long - term unemployment as an inspiration
I-Y Jung (2007)
A comparative study of social assistance schemes in Korea and eight OECD countriesSocial Welfare Policy, 31
(2009)
Labor-management relations in Korea: From confrontation to negotiation
(2014)
The development of welfare regimes in South Korea and Taiwan
(2005)
Japan’s strategic transition to a knowledge-based economy
(2008)
The process, characteristics and causes of the establishment of the Korean social security system
(2001)
The reform and development of vocational and technical education in Taiwan and its inspiration to us. Vocational and Technical Education
(2016)
2016a. A study on the relationship between skills and competitiveness of Japanese firms
(2018)
The development and evolution of the Japanese vocational education system
(1988)
Strategies for economic development in postwar Japan
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations
(1986)
A re-examination of the post-war Japanese economic development model- did Japan pursue an export-oriented strategy from the post-war period to the mid-1960s? Japanese Studies
(2009)
A review of the Japanese social assistance system under familism. Japanese Studies
(2012)
Comparison of trade union development in Japan and Korea and its implications
Seok-Joh Hong (2009)
The Social Security System in Korea
(1998)
Characteristics of Korean firms’ technological innovation strategies. China Industrial Economics
(1997)
An examination of the situation of labor-management relations in Taiwan since the restoration
(2016)
Recovering the family: Reconstructing the social foundation of modern nation-building
D. Yamamoto (2012)
Geographical political economy of regional inequality in postwar Japan
(2002)
An analysis of the current unemployment problem in Taiwan
(2011)
A comparison of Chinese and Korean social policies under the east
(2017)
Family change and family policy reconfiguration in contemporary Japan: Intergenerational redistribution of public resources
(2004)
The choice of Taiwan’s export-oriented industrialization strategy and the reasons for its successful implementation
(1998)
The legal system of unemployment insurance in Japan
(2016)
Recent reforms of Japan's social assistance system and its implications for China
(2011)
Taiwan’s social welfare system, its experience and inspiration
H. Togt (2003)
Publisher's NoteJ. Netw. Comput. Appl., 26
Yiwen Yang, Theresa Greaney (2017)
Economic growth and income inequality in the Asia-Pacific region: A comparative study of China, Japan, South Korea, and the United StatesJournal of Asian Economics, 48
(2005)
The historical evolution of human resource management in Korean enterprises. Human Resources Development of China
(2002)
Gender and welfare state restructuring in Japan
G Esping-Andersen (1999)
10.1093/0198742002.001.0001Social foundations of postindustrial economies
Masayuki Morikawa (2010)
Labor unions and productivity: An empirical analysis using Japanese firm-level dataLabour Economics, 17
John Agresto (1983)
The Humanities and the Social SciencesPS: Political Science & Politics, 16
M. Popa (2020)
Political Machines and the Institutional Background of Economic MiraclesGovernment and Opposition, 56
(2000)
Japan's labor market system and the challenges and new changes it faces
F. Christiansen (2006)
A Political Explanation of Economic Growth: State Survival, Bureaucratic Politics, and Private Enterprises in the Making of Taiwan's Economy, 1950-1985
(2004)
Asian Review of Political Economy
(2000)
The knowledge economy and Japan’s economic recession
(2012)
https:// d1wqt xts1x zle7. cloud front. net/ 56739 823/ 0B44B C76-3752-4316-A604-15C61 B9E70 7C-with-cover-page-v2. pdf?
D. Soskice, Margarita Estévez-Abe, Torben Iversen (2001)
Social protection and the formation of skills: a reinterpretation of the welfare state
(1997)
New trends in the development of Korean firms
Hayato Kobayashi (2014)
The Future of the Public Assistance Reform in Japan: Workfare versus Basic Income?
(2012)
Technological innovation, development stages and strategic choices in science and technology: The example of Taiwan’s “Late-stage” science and technology development strategy
Søren Etzerodt (2021)
Explaining economic growth in advanced capitalist democracies: varieties of capitalism and welfare production regimesComparative European Politics, 19
(2008)
Changes in Japanese government policies to support corporate human resource development and its implications for China
(2000)
A preliminary study of the employment security system and unemployment protection in Taiwan
(2013)
Family welfare' culture and the construction of welfare system in China
Ministry of Human Resources and Social Security of the People's Republic of China. 2020. China' s social security
(2021)
Huawei unveils seven innovations in digital infrastructure, creating more value for customers
D. Jacobs (2000)
Low Public Expenditures on Social Welfare: Do East Asian Countries have a Secret?International Journal of Social Welfare, 9
T. Burchardt (2001)
The social division of welfare: Some reflections on the search for equityWelfare and Wellbeing
(2013)
Taiwan’s experience in transforming and upgrading processing trade and its implications
(2022)
Making solid progress toward common prosperity
(2002)
Problems, counseling strategies and implications for technological advancement of SMEs in Taiwan
(2015)
The causes of the informal worker problem in Korea - Centering on firm-level analysis
S. Lee (2011)
The Evolution of Welfare Production Regimes in East Asia: A Comparative Study of Korea, Japan, and TaiwanThe Korean Journal of Policy Studies
(1995)
An analysis of Japanese firms' business strategy portfolio optimization
Hong Sung-Dae, Kim Chul-Ju (2005)
The Study on Transformation of Family Structure and Orientation of Family Welfare in KoreaThe Review of Korean Studies, 8
Kuo-Ting Li (1995)
[The development of science and technology].Zdravotnicka pracovnice, 26 1
Solomon Levine, R. Dore (1987)
Flexible Rigidities: Industrial Policy and Structural Adjustment in the Japanese Economy, 1970-80The Journal of Asian Studies, 46
(2008)
The role of the Korean employment insurance system on the labor market and its insights -An analysis based on the two economic crises in 1997 and
(2012)
Social welfare , effective governance and development - The case of South Korea
(2013)
The evolution of Korea’s foreign economic strategy in the postwar period
Y Wu (2005)
10.2307/j.ctt1tg5j3pA political explanation of economic growth: State survival, bureaucratic politics, and private enterprises in the making of Taiwan’s economy, 1950–1985
N. Grinberg (2014)
From Miracle to Crisis and Back: The Political Economy of South Korean Long-Term DevelopmentJournal of Contemporary Asia, 44
Decision of the State Council on accelerating the development of modern vocational education. Official website of The State Council, The People's Republic of China
Modern apprenticeships 'with Chinese characteristics'. The People's Republic of China: Official website of
(2008)
A study of the changing attitudes of Taiwan’s trade unions in the face of privatization policies – Taiwan’s trade unions since the 1980s
(2005)
Political systems, industrial development strategies, and welfare system: Comparing Japan
(2011)
The new changes in labor relations in Japan and its implications for China - A study
F. Block, G. Esping-Andersen (2001)
Social Foundations of Postindustrial EconomiesContemporary Sociology, 30
(2011)
Characteristics and insights of human resource management in Korean enterprises
(2016)
institutional theory of the French School of Regulation
W. Choi (2020)
The Origin of the Post-War Japanese Economic Miracle : Reform Policies vs. Reverse Course in the U.S. Occupation of JapanThe Korean Journal of Japanology, 124
(2016)
Changes in East Asian familism in the context of aging -A case study of welfare policies for the elderly in Japan and Korea
(1998)
Employment systems and their changes in Japanese firms
(2021)
Comparative institutional advantage in shared prosperity: A comparative social policy research agenda
(2017)
A review of research on low-skill balance
(2000)
Structural characteristics of unemployment and employment mechanisms in postwar Japan
(1997)
Vocational training in Korean enterprises and companies
Hye-Suk Wang (2015)
Familialisation Effects of the State Welfare: Focused on the National Health Insurances in S. Korea and TaiwanAsia Pacific Journal of Social Work and Development, 25
S. Lee (2016)
Institutional legacy of state corporatism in de-industrial labour markets: a comparative study of Japan, South Korea and TaiwanSocio-economic Review, 14
kemeng@tsinghua.edu.cn This paper expands the research on how shared prosperity is achieved in East Asian School of Public Policy and Management, Tsinghua countries (regions). Based on welfare production regime theory, this paper advances a University, Beijing, China theoretical framework to link economic growth to income distribution. The main argu- ment is that the match between the skills developed by social protection systems and the needs of product market strategies is key to economic progress. The skills and the social protection systems could also influence income allocation through distribution and redistribution. The net effect of the two channels determines the result of income equality. A longitudinal exploration of Japan, Taiwan and Korea in the export-led growth period (1961–1979) and the knowledge economy period (1980–1996) supports the argument. A policy implication of the argument is that China could strategically adjust its welfare production regime to achieve shared prosperity. Keywords: Welfare production regime, Shared prosperity, Economic growth, Income distribution Introduction The rapid economic growth of the past 40 years has brought both opportunities and challenges to China. On the one hand, development has enabled China to eradicate extreme poverty and build a moderately prosperous society in all respects. On the other hand, income disparities have continued to widen (Fig. 1). As the factor-driven dividend decays, China also faces an economic slowdown in its economic transition. Under such circumstances, and with the objective of achieving happiness for all Chinese people, China has made shared prosperity an important strategic goal. Shared prosperity con- veys a message that people’s well-being must be improved through development and that people deserve equal access to development. As President Xi has pointed out, achieving shared prosperity requires the training of skilled personnel and institutional arrange- ments made for the distribution, redistribution and tertiary distribution (Xi 2022). Since China is still on its road to shared prosperity, the effectiveness of these initiatives has yet to be tested in practice. However, it is surprising to see that some East Asian coun- tries (regions) have once achieved shared prosperity without having made it an explicit goal (Japan and Taiwan are two examples; see Figs. 2 and 3). These East Asian countries ‘China’ mentioned in this paper refers to mainland China, ‘Taiwan’ refers to Taiwan, China. © The Author(s) 2022. Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the mate- rial. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http:// creat iveco mmons. org/ licen ses/ by/4. 0/. Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 2 of 25 Fig. 1 Trends of economic growth and income inequality in China, 1983–2019. Sources: GDP growth (annual %): World Bank Open Data; Gini index: The Standardized World Income Inequality Database Fig. 2 Trends of economic growth and income inequality in Japan, 1961–1995. Sources: GDP growth (annual %): World Bank Open Data; Gini index: The Standardized World Income Inequality Database (regions) are similar to China in their political traditions, cultural practices and develop- ment history. Therefore, exploring how these countries (regions) did or did not realize shared prosperity may provide some insights for China. The issue of shared prosperity in East Asian countries (regions) has raised concerns among some political economists. However, most of the studies have separately explored the two dimensions of shared prosperity, which makes the emergence of shared Political economists attribute the economic miracle in East Asian countries (regions) to government-led industrial pol- icies (Rhee 2004; Choi 2020), maladies of political institutions (Wedeman 1997; Popa 2021), the structural transforma- tion of society (Grinberg 2014), etc. Some explanations of income distribution in East Asian countries (regions) include government-led industrial policies (Koo 1984; Shin et al. 2012), redistribution policies/politics (Yamamoto 2012; Yang and Greaney 2017), etc. M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 3 of 25 Fig. 3 Trends of economic growth and income inequality in Taiwan, 1964–1995. Sources: GDP growth (annual %): CEIC; Gini index: The Standardized World Income Inequality Database prosperity difficult to understand. The introduction of shared prosperity urges the adop - tion of a theoretical perspective that reconciles growth and distribution. Welfare pro- duction regime theory is a recent attempt to do this. This theory connects growth and distribution through the concept of ‘skill formation’ (Meng 2021). However, the theory appears incompatible with explanations of the shared prosperity in East Asian coun- tries (regions). The incompatibility is reflected in two ways: since the theory originated in Western countries, it emphasizes the role of the government in skill formation but omits firms and families. However, in East Asian countries (regions), firms and families bear the majority of welfare responsibility, while the government has often been absent (Kwon 2005; Dore 2013; Hong and Kim 2005; Jacobs 2000; Rose and Shiratori 1986). In addition, welfare production regime theory focuses only on the impact of distribution on income allocation. In East Asian countries (regions), where occupational welfare and family welfare are more appreciated than in Western countries (regions), redistribution has been significant in reducing the income gap (Jung 2007; Kobayashi 2014). This paper improves the understanding of how shared prosperity is realized in East Asian countries (regions) by presenting an expanded theoretical framework based on welfare production regime theory. To make this theory suitable for East Asian studies, this paper adds occupational and family welfare to the social protection systems that had originally been limited to social welfare. In addition to distribution, this paper considers the impact of redistribution on income allocation. The paper argues that the social protection system, consisting of occupational, family and social welfare, determines the formation of particular skills. When the skills fostered by social pro- tection systems are matched with the product market strategies of enterprises, rapid economic growth can be achieved. When the two do not match, economic growth may slow. In addition, the skills developed in the economy could affect income alloca - tion through distribution channels. The income allocation could also be influenced Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 4 of 25 Fig. 4 Trends of economic growth and income inequality in Korea, 1965–1995. Sources: GDP growth (annual %): World Bank Open Data; Gini index: The Standardized World Income Inequality Database by the social protection system through redistribution channels. The result of income allocation relies on the net effect of these two channels. A case-oriented exploration of the argument will be conducted longitudinally in Japan, Taiwan, and South Korea (hereafter Korea). Both Japan and Taiwan share the experience of having acquired shared prosperity and then losing it (Figs. 2 and 3). Korea obtained only high-speed economic growth or fair income distribution during one particular period (Fig. 4). This paper chooses these three cases because they not only help to illustrate the need to expand welfare production regime theory, but they also offer some practical lessons for China’s promotion of shared prosperity. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. The second section provides a detailed account of the paper’s theoretical framework. The third section uses three cases to demonstrate the relationship between the welfare production regime, eco- nomic growth and income distribution. The last section summarizes the findings of this paper and discusses the lessons that China can learn from them. Theoretical framework A welfare production regime is ‘the set of product market strategies, employee skill trajectories, and social, economic, and political institutions that support them’ (Este- vez-Abe et al. 2001, 146). Skill formation, social protection and product market strat- egies are the three core elements of welfare production regime theory. The discussion of this paper’s theoretical framework will begin with a classification of skills. Following Estevez-Abe et al. (2001), this paper distinguishes three types of skills: firm-specific, industry-specific and general. These skills differ greatly in portability. Firm-specific skills are the least transferable. They are only valuable in the enterprise in which they are acquired. Industry-specific skills can be recognized by all enter - prises within an industry. General skills, the most mobile, can be used in any firm and M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 5 of 25 industry (148). As the transferability of skills declines, the workers who possess them are exposed to more social risks. Social protection systems with different features tend to develop different types of skills. The social, economic and political institutions that support skill formation are known as social protection systems. This paper recognizes three types of welfare in a typical social protection system: occupational, family and social. Occupational welfare refers to the benefits offered by companies to their employees. Family welfare involves the care and assistance provided by families to their members. Social welfare consists of those measures taken by the government to protect citizens from social risks. Social pro- tection systems with different characteristics are apt to cultivate different types of skills. In general, a social protection system featuring strong employment protections ensures that workers can remain with the same company for a long time. In such cases, workers would be willing to acquire firm-specific skills. In a social protection system character - ized by strong unemployment protections, however, workers’ skilled wages remain the same within the industry whether they are employed or not. Such measures would moti- vate workers to acquire industry-specific skills. However, if a social protection system provides no guarantees, workers will tend to invest in the acquisition of general skills (Estevez-Abe et al. 2001, 150–152). Specifically, occupational, family and social welfare play different roles in developing certain kinds of skills. In a social protection system, employment and unemployment protections are usually offered by occupational and social welfare, which contribute directly to the development of firm-specific or industry-specific skills. For example, companies can provide their workers with lifetime employment commitments by signing labor contracts with workers. The government can also limit the dismissal of workers by enacting relevant laws. These two measures are both examples of employment protec - tions, which would motivate workers to acquire firm-specific skills. Similarly, companies within the same industry can gather together to volunteer to offer unemployment ben - efits to the workers inside the industry, or the government can provide the unemploy - ment benefits. These two kinds of unemployment protections would encourage workers to develop industry-specific skills. In addition, occupational welfare/social welfare with no features of employment or unemployment protections, could adjust the effect that social welfare/occupational welfare characterized by strong employment protection or strong unemployment protection exert on skill formation. For example, when the gov- ernment offers employment protections or unemployment protections to workers, some kinds of occupational welfare that show no features of employment protection and unemployment protection (such as performance bonuses and in-kind subsidies) could further strengthen workers’ intentions to stay in the same company or the same indus- try. As a result, workers would be more willing to invest in acquiring firm-specific or industry-specific skills compared with situations that have no such occupational welfare. Likewise, when companies provide their workers with employment or unemployment protections, some types of social welfare with no characteristics of employment protec- tion and unemployment protection (such as medical insurance and pension) could also The discussion of ‘occupational welfare’, ‘social welfare’ and ‘family welfare’ cites Titmuss (2001) and Esping-Andersen (1999). Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 6 of 25 encourage the workers to be more willing to stay within the same company or the same industry compared with situations that have no such social welfare. Thus, the role of occupational welfare in promoting skill formation would be improved. However, when occupational and social welfare provide no employment protection or unemployment protection, workers are inclined to develop general skills. Family welfare usually cannot provide employment protection or unemployment pro- tection itself, thus failing to contribute directly to skill formation. However, family wel- fare could adjust the effect that occupational and social welfare exert on skill formation. For example, in some East Asian countries (regions) influenced by Confucian traditions, women are mainly responsible for family welfare, while men are freed from family care to a large extent. Since male workers do not need to spend much time looking after their family members, they can devote themselves to the acquisition of firm-specific or indus - try-specific skills if companies or governments provide employment or unemployment protections to lead them to develop such skills. Moreover, family welfare is supported by occupational and social welfare. The provision of family welfare depends on the income source of families. The employment and unemployment protections offered by companies or governments ensure the stability of the families’ income sources. In addi- tion, some kinds of occupational and social welfare characterized by no employment or unemployment protections (such as subsidies from companies or the government) could increase families’ income. The measures mentioned above could all enhance the ability of families to offer care and assistance to their members. Apart from social protection systems, different product market strategies require different types of skills due to their distinct production requirements. Product market strategies are the plans that companies make to promote the sales of their products. To achieve particular goals, companies with different product market strategies often adopt different modes of production. The way companies produce products determines the skills that they need. For example, companies that regard diversified varieties and high quality of their products as a competitive advantage may turn to diversified mass pro - duction or diversified quality production strategies. Both strategies require workers to command the production of multiple products. Workers are also expected to be adept at job switching and problem solving. The former strategy is suitable for the condition that the products, production techniques and specialist equipment are highly heterogeneous among companies. The latter strategy fits the circumstance that companies within an industry often share technologies. Based on the above discussion, the diversified mass production strategy requires firm-specific skills, but the diversified quality produc - tion strategy requires industry-specific skills. Among companies that sell standardized goods, affordable prices may be their comparative advantage. A Fordist mass produc - tion strategy of standardized goods could therefore be appropriate. This strategy usually breaks down the production process into several simple standardized tasks. Each worker is responsible for performing a single task. Such specialization lowers companies’ costs by reducing the skill requirements for workers. Since workers only need to command simple operations in the Fordist mass production strategy, general skills are sufficient (Estevez-Abe et al. 2001, 148–149). When skills fostered by social protection systems match the needs of product mar- ket strategies, economic progress could accelerate. The enterprise is the basic unit of M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 7 of 25 economic production. When the social protection system produces the type of skills that companies’ product market strategies need, companies will gain comparative advantages of productivity and competitiveness in the market. The vitality of enterprises underpins rapid economic growth. Although changes in the product market strategies adopted by companies are often fast, social protection systems are slow to make adjustments. The result is that the social protection systems develop skills that the companies’ product market strategies do not need, leading to companies’ loss of comparative advantages in the sales market, which may result in slowed economic growth. u Th s far, the revised welfare production regime theory presented in this paper has shown its similarities with and the difference from endogenous growth theory. As endogenous growth theory points out, the accumulation of human capital is key to tech- nological innovation. Technological progress improves production efficiency and, thus, could lead to an increase in economic growth. To boost economic development, the relevant actors (such as the government) should assume responsibility for human capi- tal investment. The revised welfare production regime theory agrees with endogenous growth theory on the above ideas, but differs from endogenous growth theory in three ways. First, endogenous growth theory usually views public education as an effective way to strengthen investment in human capital, while the revised welfare production regime theory emphasizes that the establishment of a social protection system is ben- eficial for improving the accumulation of human capital. Second, endogenous growth theory regards human capital as homogenous, while the revised welfare production regime theory subdivides the types of human capital into firm-specific, industry-specific and general skills. Third, according to endogenous growth theory, the accumulation of human capital usually promotes economic development. However, this inevitability does not hold in the revised welfare production regime theory, according to which only when the kind of human capital generated by the social protection system matches the needs of companies’ product market strategies would economic progress be achieved. In addition to economic growth, the result of skill formation could also influence income allocation through wage bargaining and skill training (referred to as distribu- tion channels). Collective wage bargaining helps to preserve the stability of income distribution among workers. Since firm-specific and industry-specific skills are less transferable than general skills, workers who invest in these two types of skills have stronger incentives to establish collective wage-bargaining systems than workers who possess general skills. The workers depend on collective wage-bargaining systems to protect their return on investment in firm-specific and industry-specific skills. One of the tasks of the systems is to conduct a joint discussion of the salary for each position. It helps to control wage disparities among workers. However, economies dominated by general skills lack the incentive to set up such systems. As a result, the income gaps are often larger there (Estevez-Abe et al. 2001, 155). For skill training, the insti- tutionalized ‘from-school-to-work’ transition contributes to narrowing the income gap among workers. Both on-the-job training for firm-specific skills and vocational school training for industry-specific skills are institutionalized ‘from-school-to- work’ shifts. In such practices, students have equal access to the labor market. Even the least competent students can earn a decent income. Noninstitutionalized shifts (such as academic education systems for general skills), however, are connected with Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 8 of 25 Fig. 5 The relationship between the welfare production regime, economic growth and income equality. *The thick arrows within the social protection system represent the direct and indirect effects of occupational, social and family welfare on skill formation. The thin arrows within the social protection system represent the role of occupational welfare/social welfare in supporting family welfare. Not all the arrows within the social protection system appear in all the cases in reality unclear career prospects. Such shifts usually weed the less capable students out of the labor market. This may widen the potential income gap between skilled and less- skilled workers. In summary, the institutionalized ‘from-school-to-work’ transition was beneficial for narrowing the income gap in the labor market (Estevez-Abe et al. 2001, 156–158). Except for skill formation, income allocation could also be affected by social pro - tection systems through family welfare and social welfare (referred to as redistribu- tion channels). The income transfers within families help to narrow the income gap between workers and nonworkers. Family welfare is often reflected in the care and assistance offered by families to their members, including nonworkers. Such prac - tices depend on the income of employed family members. In this way, income is redistributed from workers to nonworkers, which helps to prevent income dispari- ties from increasing. Moreover, the government uses tax and social welfare to real- locate resources from the employed to the unemployed in society. The government usually collects tax revenue from the employed. Part of these revenues would be used to improve the living conditions of vulnerable groups in the form of social welfare (such as social assistance). Such redistributive measures shift income from higher- to lower-income groups (or even people outside of the workforce), which contributes to the reduction of income inequality. It is worth noting that the distribution and redistribution mechanisms may exert the same or opposite influence on income allocation. Whether the final result of income distribution is equitable relies on the net effect of these two channels. Figure 5 illustrates the theoretical framework presented in this paper. The social protection system, consisting of occupational, family and social welfare, determines what type of skills would be developed in an economy. If the skills fostered are matched with the product market strategies of the companies, then rapid economic M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 9 of 25 growth would be achieved. Otherwise, economic growth may slow. Income distribu- tion is influenced by the distribution and redistribution channels, with the former driven by skill formation and the latter backed by social protection systems. The out - come of income distribution depends on the net effect of these two channels. In the following section, the theoretical framework described above will be used to explain how Japan, Taiwan and Korea did or did not achieve shared prosperity. The purpose of the discussion is not only to test the revised theoretical framework but also to strengthen the understanding of shared prosperity in East Asian countries (regions). Exploring the argument: evidence from three cases This section applies the theoretical framework to conduct a longitudinal study of Japan, Taiwan and Korea. The experience of these three countries (regions) is divided into two periods: export-led growth (1961–1979) and the knowledge economy (1980–1996). For each period, this paper will compare the similarities and differences of these countries (regions) in terms of welfare production regimes and shared prosperity. Export‑led growth period: 1961–1979 Product market strategies Although Japan, Taiwan and Korea all adopted import substitution strategies in the 1950s, they chose different industries to protect based on their distinct historical situ - ations. Japan’s light industry had been growing since the late nineteenth century, and by the 1950s, it was competitive in the world market. Japan could use foreign exchange earned from exports of light industrial products (as well as US aid) to support the devel- opment of heavy domestic industries (such as cars, household appliances and electron- ics) (Jin 1986). However, neither Taiwan nor Korea possessed any competitive products for export at that time. This resulted in a scarcity of foreign exchange. In addition, these two regions (countries) could not produce all essential goods themselves. To solve the problem of production deficiency without adding pressure to foreign exchange short - ages, Taiwan and Korea chose to build independent production capacity first instead of purchasing directly from abroad. Light industry (such as plastics, glass, textiles, and cement), which serves everyday needs, was prioritized for development (Jiang and Yang 2013; Wu 2005, 104–131). Attributed to the protection received in this period, Japan’s heavy industry and Taiwan’s and Korea’s light industries acquired comparative advan- tages in exports. However, by the end of the 1950s, the dilemma faced by Japan, Taiwan and Korea urged them to turn to export-led growth strategies. As the import substitution strate- gies were carried out, Japan, Taiwan and Korea all suffered from a balance of payment deficits, high inflation, local overproduction and economic stagnation. In addition, in the late 1950s, US aid, which was essential for sustaining the import substitution strat- egies, was cut. The problems mentioned above called for a strategic transformation in Japan, Taiwan and Korea. Considering the small local market and inadequate resources, the three countries (regions) believed that taking advantage of outside markets was critical to their future economic development. Therefore, all three countries (regions) shifted to export-led growth strategies in the 1960s (Liu and Zhou 2016; Ren 1988; Wu 2005, 132–233; Zhang 2004). Due to the divergent development paths during the import Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 10 of 25 substitution strategy phase, Japan chose heavy industry, while Taiwan and Korea chose light industry as their leading export industry. According to the distinctive requirements of their export industries, firms in Japan, Taiwan and Korea adopted different product market strategies. In Japan, companies regard abundant variety and reliable quality as their competitive advantage in the export market of heavy industry products. To achieve a competitive advantage, they applied the diversified mass production strategy to production (Qian 1995). In Japanese companies, workers usually operated several product lines simultaneously. They were also expected to solve problems on their own (Liu 2016a). To meet these requirements, highly spe- cialized skills were needed. Moreover, since the products, production techniques and mechanical equipment were heterogeneous among Japanese companies, such special- ized skills were tied to firms, not industries. In summary, Japanese companies required firm-specific skills to conduct a diversified mass production strategy. In contrast, in Tai - wan and Korea, where exports were driven by light industry, the situations were differ - ent. Unlike Japanese companies, Taiwanese and Korean firms tried to gain comparative advantages in the export market by cutting prices and expanding supply. To realize these goals, companies needed to minimize labor costs while engaging in mass production (Kuang 2013; Liu and Wang 2011). A Fordist mass production strategy of standardized goods was thus suitable. Under this strategy, workers only needed to perform a specific standardized task instead of mastering the production of diversified products. Such spe - cialization not only facilitated mass production but also reduced skill requirements for workers. According to the discussion in Theoretical framework section, general skills were sufficient to meet demand. This kind of skill did not require the companies to pro - vide much training or to pay a high return, satisfying companies’ desire for cost savings. In conclusion, Taiwanese and Korean companies needed workers with general skills to carry out the Fordist mass production strategy. Social protection, skill formation and economic growth Although Japan, Taiwan and Korea presented different kinds of social protection sys - tems in the export-led growth period, the skills developed by these systems all met the needs of product market strategies. The match between skills and strategies helped to improve economic performance. In Japan, firm-specific skills fostered by the social protection system met the require - ments of the diversified mass production strategy, boosting economic growth. Japan’s social protection system is characterized by strong employment protection and weak unemployment protection. Employment protection in Japan was led by occupational welfare. To motivate workers to invest in firm-specific skills, Japanese companies pro - vided lifetime employment commitments, seniority-based wage systems and internal promotion to their workers (Zhao 2000). Employment protection offered by occupa - tional welfare was supported by family and social welfare. The traditional Japanese fam - ily, influenced by Confucianism, was accustomed to having men work in the paid labor force while women performed unpaid labor at home. This mode of life freed Japanese men from family caregiving responsibilities. u Th s, they could devote themselves to skill acquisition and everyday work (Peng 2002). In addition, although the Japanese govern- ment adopted a ‘residual welfare’ pattern, it still provided some support for occupational M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 11 of 25 welfare. For example, the government established the National Pension Plan to enhance the credibility of employment protection offered by companies (Shizume et al. 2021). The government also helped to reinforce family welfare. For instance, to improve fami - lies’ caring function, the government gave subsidies to families with children (Peng 2000). However, strict unemployment protections in Japan were not found in occupa- tional, family or social welfare. The exception is unemployment insurance introduced by the government in 1947. According to the law, unemployment benefits were available on a narrow scale, and the jobless could receive up to 30% of their preunemployment wages (Xu and Li 1998). Since workers did not obtain a reliable guarantee of maintaining the same skilled wages, they lacked the incentives to invest in industry-specific skills. In short, the social protection system motivated Japanese workers to acquire firm-specific skills. The skills matched the diversified mass production strategy that most Japanese companies adopted, contributing to the country’s rapid economic growth. In Taiwan and Korea, the social protection systems motivated workers to acquire general skills. The match between the skills and the requirements of the Fordist mass production strategy also contributed to economic progress. Unlike Japan, Taiwan’s and Korea’s social protection systems presented both weak employment and unemploy- ment protections. Taiwanese and Korean workers usually compete in the external labor market, not in the internal labor market (Lee 2011; Zhao and Tan 1996). In addition, unemployment insurance systems were not introduced in Taiwan and Korea until the late 1990s (Song and Wang 2003; Zhang 2011). This means that the workers in Taiwan and Korea were neither offered a long-term commitment to work within the same com - pany nor were their skilled wages protected within the same industry. They were, there - fore, willing to invest in general skills. This kind of skill was consistent with the Fordist mass production strategy implemented by most Taiwanese and Korean firms. The match between the skills and the product market strategies helped to accelerate the economic growth of the two regions (countries). Distribution, redistribution and income equality Owing to the different skills formed by social protection systems, Japan, Taiwan and Korea behaved differently in terms of distribution. The establishment of collective wage-bargaining systems in Japan had a positive effect on income equality among workers, while the absence of such systems in Taiwan and Korea had a negative effect. To ensure a sustainable return on skill acquisition, Japanese workers who possessed firm-specific skills had the incentive to form unions. Unions enhanced their members’ bargaining power against the employers. One task of unions is to engage in collective wage bargaining. In Japan, in addition to raising workers’ salaries, collective wage bargaining was intended to preserve seniority-based wage systems. In such systems, the wage disparity between workers with different years of seniority was limited (Lv 2011; Morikawa 2010; Zhao and Zhao 2006), which helped to reduce income inequality. However, workers with general skills in Taiwan and Korea had fewer incen- tives to form unions. Moreover, to maintain political stability, the military regimes in Taiwan and Korea prohibited any self-organization, including unions (Li and Zhao 2008; Yang 2008). Therefore, the absence of collective wage bargaining failed to resolve income equality among Taiwanese and Korean workers. Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 12 of 25 For skill training, Japan and Taiwan’s institutionalized ‘from-school-to-work’ transfor- mation helped reduce income disparities among workers, but the noninstitutionalized shift in Korea may have had the opposite effect. Japanese workers usually acquired firm- specific skills from the training offered by companies. Furthermore, to ensure a smooth transition from school to the workplace, companies often cooperated with vocational schools in terms of internships and recruitment (Qi and Wang 2018; Sang 2012). Based on the discussion in Theoretical framework section, this institutionalized ‘from-school- to-work’ transformation helped prevent the income gap from widening. In Taiwan and Korea, although both economies were dominated by general skills, they behaved differ - ently in terms of skill training. Taiwan’s economy is based on small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs). Since SMEs usually could not afford to provide training, Taiwan relied on its public vocational schools to train semiskilled workers. In public vocational training systems, even students who graduated at the bottom of their class could find a job as long as they acquired skill certification (Zhang 2001). This practice is close to an institutionalized ‘from-school-to-work’ transformation. It could therefore contribute to income equality among workers. In Korea, the economy is dominated by large compa- nies. Unlike SMEs in Taiwan, large companies in Korea could provide training to their workers once workers were employed. However, since academic qualifications are an important recruitment criterion for Korean companies, workers prefer to complete their academic education before entering the labor market (Wang 2017). Nevertheless, aca- demic education systems did not guarantee a job to every graduate, who often competed for jobs; in such a competitive labor market, only the most capable individuals stood out. Such a noninstitutionalized shift may have widened the income gap among workers. Although Japan, Taiwan and Korea behaved differently in terms of distribution, they presented similar performances in redistribution due to the similar conditions of family welfare and social assistance. For family welfare, the influence of Confucianism helped reinforce income equality between workers and nonworkers. In these three countries (regions), people preferred to live with their extended families. In such families, men were the sole source of income, and women relied on men’s salaries to take care of the family members (Liu 2016b; Peng 2002; Yan 1997). In other words, family welfare was supported by occupational welfare. The transfer of income from workers to nonwork - ers within families helped close the income gap between them. Moreover, social assis- tance provided by the government also helped to reduce income disparities between the employed and the unemployed. Although all three countries (regions) prioritized eco- nomic development over social security, the governments offered social assistance to nonworkers without families. Governments used tax revenue collected from workers to provide nonworkers with relief services (Han et al. 2011; Liu 2014; Peng 2000; Shizume et al. 2021; Sun 2011). Such a redistribution shifted resources from the employed to the unemployed, which helped to narrow the income gap. General skills usually do not require advanced training like firm-specific and industry-specific skills do, but workers still need some training. There are many kinds of social welfare with redistributive functions in a country’s (region’s) social protection system. This paper focuses on social welfare which could influence the income disparity between workers and nonworkers. Social assistance is a typical example. M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 13 of 25 Fig. 6 Welfare production regime, economic growth and income equality in Japan during the export-led growth period. * The thick arrows within the social protection system represent the direct and indirect effects of occupational, social and family welfare on skill formation. The thin arrows within the social protection system represent the role of occupational welfare/social welfare in supporting family welfare. * ‘+’ represents the positive effect on income equality, while ‘-’ represents the negative effect on income equality Fig. 7 Welfare production regime, economic growth and income equality in Taiwan during the export-led growth period (In the figures presented in this paper, the arrows between occupational, family and social welfare only represent their relationship in terms of employment protection or unemployment protection. The absence of arrows in the figures does not imply that these three kinds of welfare are unconnected.). * The thick arrows within the social protection system represent the direct and indirect effects of occupational, social and family welfare on skill formation. The thin arrows within the social protection system represent the role of occupational welfare/social welfare in supporting family welfare. * ‘+’ represents the positive effect on income equality, while ‘-’ represents the negative effect on income equality With different combinations of distribution and redistribution policies, Japan, Taiwan and Korea obtained different results in income allocation. Japan and Taiwan presented equal income allocation, while Korea’s income inequality rose. In conclusion, affected by all of the mechanisms mentioned above, Japan and Taiwan achieved shared prosperity in the stage of export-led growth (Figs. 6 and 7), while Korea failed to do so (Fig. 8). Korea acquired rapid economic growth, but its income inequality worsened. Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 14 of 25 Fig. 8 Welfare production regime, economic growth and income equality in Korea during the export-led growth period. * The thick arrows within the social protection system represent the direct and indirect effects of occupational, social and family welfare on skill formation. The thin arrows within the social protection system represent the role of occupational welfare/social welfare in supporting family welfare. * ‘+’ represents the positive effect on income equality, while ‘-’ represents the negative effect on income equality Knowledge economy period: 1980–1996 Product market strategies Since the 1980s, changes in the domestic and international environment have prompted companies from Japan, Taiwan and Korea to resort to new product mar- ket strategies. During this period, rising labor costs and the appreciation of cur- rency reduced Japan’s, Taiwan’s and Korea’s comparative advantages in the export market relative to other developing countries (regions). Moreover, as protection- ism rose internationally, it became more difficult for them to introduce technologies from abroad to make use of the latecomer’s advantages than before (Liu 2000, 2005; Yan 2002). With rapid development in the export-led growth period, the difference between the three countries (regions) and other developed countries (regions) was diminished. This means that the latecomer’s advantages on which Japan, Taiwan and Korea had once depended were less of a factor. With the chase of the less developing countries (regions) and the interception of the more developed countries (regions), companies in these three countries (regions) were eager to transform their product market strategies. The knowledge economy that emerged in the 1980s guided companies in Japan, Tai - wan and Korea to adopt product market strategies characterized by radical innova- tion. Such strategies demanded more advanced general skills than those developed in Taiwan and Korea during the export-led growth period. In the 1980s, the knowledge economy began acquiring dominant status in international competition, when mar- ginal improvements to products were no longer enough to help companies to sustain their competitive advantage in the export market. Radical innovation replaced incre- mental innovation as the source of companies’ competitiveness. In this context, Japa- nese, Taiwanese and Korean firms tried to transform their product market strategies into radical innovation, increasing input in the research and development (R&D) of independent technologies (He 2000; Huang 1997; Li 2000; Song 1998). Since radical M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 15 of 25 innovation is usually born from the integration of multidisciplinary knowledge and cross-industry experience, workers with skills tied to a particular firm or industry may hinder such innovation. Instead, general skills were suitable for radical innova- tion (Estevez-Abe et al. 2001, 145–183; Etzerodt 2021). Although these skills were similar to the general skills required by the Fordist mass production strategy in terms of portability, they were inherently different. The general skills required by radical innovation required that workers apply their creative thinking to production, while the general skills needed by the Fordist mass production strategy only required work- ers to perform simple operations repeatedly. Therefore, the general skills required in the era of the knowledge economy were more advanced than those developed by Tai- wanese and Korean workers during the previous export-led growth period. Social protection, skill formation and economic growth Although companies in Japan, Taiwan and Korea all wished to apply radical innovation to their product market strategies, their social protection systems failed to meet the needs of the strategies. The skills fostered by the social protection systems were incom - patible with the requirements of radical innovation, hindering economic development in these three countries (regions). In Japan, the slow adjustment of the social protection system led to the failure to instill the general skills that radical innovation called for. This mismatch was detrimental to economic growth. Under the pressure of transformation, Japanese companies tried to reduce employment protection. Because of resistance from groups with vested interests (such as unions), the changes were limited. For example, in an effort to maintain lifelong employment, Japanese companies chose to restrict recruitment and hire informal work- ers instead. Moreover, although ability and performance were introduced in the evalu- ation system, seniority remained the critical determinant of promotion (Chen 1998; Lee 2016). These attempts did not alter the reality of strong employment protections in terms of occupational welfare. However, Japan’s family welfare and social welfare which used to support occupational welfare, declined. With women’s increased participation in the labor force and the shrinkage of family size, the Japanese family’s caring function was weakened. In addition, the aging of the population exacerbated the burden of fam- ily care (Ma 2017). The reduction in caring capacity conflicted with increased responsi - bilities. This contradiction made it impossible for family welfare to support occupational welfare. Regarding social welfare, because of the financial crisis, the Japanese govern - ment reduced its support for occupational welfare by decreasing the average benefits of employment insurance (Huang 2010). At the same time, the introduction of ‘the Jap- anese-type welfare society’ called for a return of welfare responsibility to individuals, families and society. Thus, the government implemented subsidies and tax reductions to enhance family welfare (Lou and Wang 2016). Although support from family welfare and social welfare decreased, the social protection system still presented strong employ- ment protection (Table 1). In addition to employment protection, unemployment pro- tection remained almost the same in Japan. Japan replaced unemployment insurance As Table 1 depicts, although Japan’s strictness index of employment protection is lower than the average of OECD countries, it is still much higher than countries dominated by general skills, such as the United States. Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 16 of 25 Table 1 Strictness of employment protection in some OECD countries in 1995 Regular contracts Temporary contracts Japan 1.70 1.69 Korea 3.08 3.13 United States 0.09 0.25 United Kingdom 1.35 0.25 Sweden 2.64 1.77 Germany 2.60 3.13 Average 2.26 2.05 Sources: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) Database The regular contracts include individual and collective dismissals The average value is calculated on the data of 28 OECD countries that the database has records for in 1995 with employment insurance in 1974 but was unable to sustain the skilled wages of work- ers (Chen 2017), thus failing to cultivate industry-specific skills. In summary, Japan’s social protection system was characterized by strong employment protections and weak unemployment protections. Thus, firm-specific skills were the dominant skills devel - oped by such a system. However, since employment protections had relaxed, this social protection system also generated some general skills. The discrepancy between skills and the need for radical innovation led to the slowdown of economic growth. Although Taiwan’s social protection system preserved weak employment and weak unemployment protections, it failed to cultivate the general skills needed for radical innovation. As a result, Taiwan’s economic growth slowed. In the knowledge economy period, Taiwan’s workers were still not offered guarantees to stay with a particular com - pany or industry (Wang 2000); thus, they competed with all other workers in the labor market. Such a social protection system seemed conducive to developing the general skills that radical innovation needed. However, the expectation was not fulfilled. Due to the small number and high mobility of employees, SMEs in Taiwan lacked the resources and willingness to invest in R&D and training workers. Since these tasks were essential to the transformation of product market strategies, the government bore the responsibil- ity. In its scientific and technological innovation planning, the government emphasized the low-end links of the production chain (such as production techniques) instead of the development of key technologies. The lack of input and the ignorance of the impor - tance of fostering talent for advanced technology rendered the advanced general skills required by radical innovation insufficient in Taiwan (Li 2012). Although Taiwan’s social protection system helped foster general skills, they were low-end and incompatible with the needs of the product market strategies, hindering Taiwan’s economic progress. In Korea, the strengthening of employment protections made the social protection system fail to cultivate the skills needed for radical innovation. As a result, economic growth slowed. Although Korea’s social protection system offered no unemploy - ment protection (Zhang 2011), it enhanced employment protection. In the mid-1980s, democratization created conditions for the formation of labor movements. In these movements, workers fought for more guarantees to protect themselves from social risk. To mitigate conflicts and sustain social stability, the government guided companies to establish internal labor markets. The dismissal of workers was then strictly limited by M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 17 of 25 law, and companies established seniority-based wage systems (Cheng 2015; Fang 2005; Wu 2011). Like Japan’s, Korea’s employment protection was led by occupational welfare. Korea’s family welfare was also affected by the growing number of professional women, the decreasing number of extended families and the aging of the population (Jin and Du 2020; Shen 2016). u Th s, the supporting role of Korea’s family welfare was under - mined. However, Korea’s social welfare was promoted by democratization. To respond to the appeal of the people, the government compensated for the lack of support for occupational welfare during the export-led growth period by offering pensions, medical insurance and employment insurance to ensure the stability of employment protections offered by companies. It also reduced the tax burden on families with elderly members to enhance families’ caring functions (Li 1998). In short, although support from fam- ily welfare declined, the social protection system in Korea still offered growing employ - ment protections (Table 1) and weak unemployment protections. Such a system tended to foster a mix of firm-specific and general skills. However, these skills were incompat - ible with product market strategies that featured radical innovation, exerting an adverse effect on Korea’s economic development. Distribution, redistribution and income equality Due to the changes in skill formation and the social environment, Japan, Taiwan and Korea behaved differently in terms of distribution. The weakening of collective wage bargaining in Japan was disadvantageous to income equality among workers, while the establishment of collective wage bargaining in Tai- wan and Korea helped reduce inequality. In Japan, although the adjustments toward the development of general skills were slow, they still weakened the influence of the enterprise unions. The number of Japanese enterprise unions and their members had decreased significantly since the mid-1980s (Liu 2012). Therefore, it became harder for unions to limit income disparities among workers than before. In Taiwan and Korea, democratization gave workers the legal right to organize unions. After the social move- ment occurred in the late 1980s, the number of unions and union membership grew rapidly in Taiwan and Korea. With the help of the collective wage-bargaining systems implemented by unions, Taiwanese and Korean workers demanded higher salaries and more stable income distribution (Wang 2009; Yang 1997). The transition from vocational training to academic education in Japan and Taiwan contributed to the widening income gap between workers and nonworkers, but the reverse transition aggravated income equality in Korea. As the form of employment diversified, Japanese companies became reluctant to provide on-the-job training. The number of companies that provided on-the-job training decreased dramatically dur- ing the knowledge economy period (Ping et al. 2008). The introduction of ability in the employees’ evaluation systems also helped to promote academic education. These changes contributed to a less institutionalized ‘from-school-to-work’ transforma- tion than before and led to rising income inequality in the labor market. In Taiwan, to upgrade general skills, the vocational training system became multilayered. The As Table 1 depicts, Korea’s strictness index of employment protections is higher than that of Japan and the average of OECD countries. Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 18 of 25 Fig. 9 Welfare production regime, economic growth and income equality in Japan during the knowledge economy period. * The thick arrows within the social protection system represent the direct and indirect effects of occupational, social and family welfare on skill formation. The thin arrows within the social protection system represent the role of occupational welfare/social welfare in supporting family welfare. * ‘+’ represents the positive effect on income equality, while ‘-’ represents the negative effect on income equality. ‘↑’ indicates that the effect is increasing, while ‘↓’ indicates that the effect is declining. Arrows in dashed lines represent that the influence is weakening introduction of undergraduate, postgraduate and doctoral education made the voca- tional training system in Taiwan resemble an academic education system. This change undermined the ability of vocational training to support income equality (Chen and He 2011). In Korea, the development of internal labor markets was accompanied by the emergence of on-the-job training by companies (Shang 1997). Although this form of skill training impeded the acquisition of general skills, it helped narrow the income gap among workers. Although Japan, Taiwan and Korea behaved differently in terms of distribution, they all presented a weakening redistribution role in boosting income equality between workers and nonworkers due to a convergence of the similar conditions of unemploy- ment, family welfare and social assistance. During this period, the economic slow- down, the industry transformation and the growing number of female job seekers led to rising unemployment rates in these three countries (regions) (Lin 2002; Lin and Feng 1999; Zhang 2000). It thus became harder for redistribution to cover the income disparities between workers and nonworkers. In Japan, Taiwan and Korea, family wel- fare and social assistance failed to bear the burden. In addition to the weakening of the caring function and the increase in caring responsibilities, family welfare received fewer benefits from occupational welfare than before due to the economic slowdown ( Jin and Du 2020; Ma 2017; Shen 2016; Wang 2015). These problems blunted the pos - itive effect of income transfer within families. Furthermore, there was no dramatic improvement in terms of social assistance. The limited changes are reflected in the expansion of the scope of assistance (Lv 2016; Ringen et al. 2012; Zhao 2009; Zou 2012). The weakening of family welfare and the minor improvements of social assis - tance made it impossible for redistribution to reduce the income disparity between workers and nonworkers caused by rising unemployment rates. With different combinations of distribution and redistribution, Japan, Taiwan and Korea arrived at distinct results in terms of income allocation. Both Japan and Taiwan M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 19 of 25 Fig. 10 Welfare production regime, economic growth and income equality in Taiwan during the knowledge economy period. * The thick arrows within the social protection system represent the direct and indirect effects that occupational, social and family welfare exert on skill formation. The thin arrows within the social protection system represent the role of occupational welfare/social welfare in supporting family welfare. * ‘+’ represents the positive effect on income equality, while ‘-’ represents the negative effect on income equality. ‘↑’ indicates that the effect is increasing, while ‘↓’ indicates that the effect is declining. Arrows in dashed lines represent that the influence is weakening Fig. 11 Welfare production regime, economic growth and income equality in Korea during the knowledge economy period. * The thick arrows within the social protection system represent the direct and indirect effects that occupational, social and family welfare exert on skill formation. The thin arrows within the social protection system represent the role of occupational welfare/social welfare in supporting family welfare. * ‘+’ represents the positive effect on income equality, while ‘-’ represents the negative effect on income equality. ‘↑’ indicates that the effect is increasing, while ‘↓’ indicates that the effect is declining. Arrows in dashed lines represent that the influence is weakening experienced rising income inequality, while Korea enjoyed greater income equality than in the previous period. In conclusion, affected by all the mechanisms mentioned above, Japan and Taiwan sac - rificed shared prosperity in the knowledge economy phase (Figs. 9 and 10). Although Korea obtained equal income distribution, its economic growth slowed (Fig. 11). Discussion and conclusions This paper improves the understanding of how shared prosperity was achieved in East Asian countries (regions) from a political economy perspective. Based on welfare pro- duction regime theory, this paper presents a revised theoretical framework in which skill formation links economic growth to income distribution. Since the political Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 20 of 25 economy literature usually explores economic growth and income distribution sepa- rately, this paper complements and expands the literature on the emergence of shared prosperity. In addition, since welfare production regime theory fails to fit East Asian studies owing to its omission of some essential elements, occupational welfare, family welfare and redistribution are added to the revised theoretical framework. The frame - work thus extended the scope of the application of welfare production regime theory, making it possible to explore shared prosperity in the context of East Asian countries (regions). This paper explains how shared prosperity is realized in East Asian countries (regions): social protection systems, consisting of occupational, family and social welfare, are key to developing particular skills. When the skills are consistent with the needs of product market strategies adopted by companies, economic progress improves. Otherwise, a mismatch may undermine or slow economic development. Skill formation and social protection could influence income allocation, with the former often occurring in the distribution channel and the latter frequently being observed in the redistribution channel. These two channels may involve multiple mechanisms with distinct effects on income allocation, the result of which relies on the net effect of these mechanisms. The argument has been supported by the histori - cal analyses of Japan, Taiwan and Korea. However, much work remains to be done to explore the details of the theoretical framework. One task is to examine the logic of the framework quantitatively. This theoretical framework can produce many hypotheses. Compared with a case study, quantitative research could identify causal mechanisms more accurately. It is also possible to extend the argument in this paper to other East Asian countries (regions) or historical periods. The three cases examined in this paper are typical. Applying the analysis to outlying or special cases may enhance the external validity of the framework. A further policy implication of the argument in this paper is that China could adopt strategic measures to achieve shared prosperity. To avoid falling into the middle- income trap, China could establish a multilayered social protection system to adapt to the skill needs of different product market strategies of companies from different industries. For example, although China is a competitor in the knowledge economy, there are regional variations in terms of development within China. Some companies in the eastern provinces of China (such as Huawei) have already joined the race of radical innovation in the world market (Huawei 2021). To foster the advanced gen- eral skills required by such product market strategies, the social protection system should provide workers with employment flexibility. The skill training system should increase the input in the cultivation of skills for key technologies; otherwise, it risks failing to develop the skills needed by radical innovation, as happened in Taiwan in the 1990s. In some central and western provinces, capital-intensive industries (such as manufacturing) remain the leading industries. As China’s comparative advantage in low labor costs declines in these industries, companies in the international market compete to offer products with the greatest diversity and quality (The State Coun - cil Information Office of the People’s Republic of China 2022). Such product market strategies require industry-specific skills. To instill these skills, the social protection M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 21 of 25 system should offer unemployment protection. The launch of modern apprenticeship pilot projects in China is a recent attempt in this direction (Ministry of Education, The People’s Republic of China 2018). In conclusion, enabling the social protection system to develop the skills that firms’ product market strategies require is key to eco - nomic success. Regarding income allocation, collective wage bargaining could play a more prom- inent role in enhancing income equality among workers, while the development of vocational education in China should strike a balance between cultivating the skills needed and promoting income equality. Although workers with firm-specific or industry-specific skills have more incentives to establish collective wage-bargaining systems, such systems could also be established in industries dominated by work- ers with general skills. For example, China is building a collective wage-bargaining mechanism in the express delivery industry, where highly mobile workers usually possess general skills (State Post Bureau of The People’s Republic of China 2021). Col - lective wage bargaining is useful in limiting income disparities among workers. In the future, it may help to promote shared prosperity in China. However, care should be taken when depending on vocational education to narrow the income gap. China is now aggressively promoting vocational education (The State Council, The People’s Republic of China 2014). Cultivating the talent that the country needs, not facilitating income equality, is the purpose of this measure. Since the form of skill training is cru- cial to the fostering of skills, the development of vocational education should balance the needs of product market strategies and the promotion of income equality. Focus- ing only on income equality while ignoring skill requirements may prove an impedi- ment to economic progress. In terms of redistribution, social welfare may play a more active part in increasing income equality between workers and nonworkers than family welfare in China. Like Japan, Taiwan and Korea, China has long been influenced by Confucianism. The income transfer within families has also been important in China’s redistribution. As more females join the labor force, the size of families decreases and the population ages, China faces the problem of weakening family welfare (Luo 2013), similar to the cases of Japan, Taiwan and Korea. It has therefore become more difficult for family welfare to assume a leading role in improving income equality. However, social welfare may still have a chance. China prioritized economic development over social security, as Japan, Taiwan and Korea once did. In the past 40 years, although the government has put much effort into building and improving the social security system, it is still far from perfect (Min- istry of Human Resources and Social Security of the People’s Republic of China 2020). Apart from social assistance, measures such as offering services for elderly individuals, children and women could also help to close the income gap between workers and non- workers. In the future, there is much room for social welfare to bring shared prosperity to China. Authors’ contributions All authors are involved in theory construction, case analysis and article writing. All author(s) read and approved the final manuscript. Funding Not applicable. Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 22 of 25 Availability of data and materials Not applicable. Declarations Competing interests The authors declare that they have no competing interests. Received: 30 March 2022 Accepted: 5 July 2022 References Chen, Jianan. 1998. Employment systems and their changes in Japanese firms. Japanese Studies (5): 75–88 (in Chinese). Chen, Lin. 2017. The key orientation of the construction of China’s unemployment protection system – Taking Japan’s experience in combating long-term unemployment as an inspiration. Modern Economic Research (5): 16–22. https:// doi. org/ 10. 13891/j. cnki. mer. 2017. 05. 003 (in Chinese). Chen, Suoqing, and Yuhong He. 2011. The development of higher vocational education in Taiwan and its implication to Mainland China. Education and Vocation (14): 74–76. https:// doi. org/ 10. 13615/j. cnki. 1004- 3985. 2011. 14. 082 (in Chinese). Cheng, Duowen. 2015. The causes of the informal worker problem in Korea - Centering on firm-level analysis. Collected Papers for Korean Studies (2): 214–230 (in Chinese). Choi, Woondo. 2020. The origin of the post-war Japanese economic miracle: Reform policies vs. reverse course in the U.S. occupation of Japan. The Korean Journal of Japanology (124): 257–282. https:// doi. org/ 10. 15532/ kaja. 2020. 08. 124. Dore, Ronald. 2013. Flexible rigidities: Industrial policy and structural adjustment in the Japanese economy, 1970–1980. Lon- don: Bloomsbury Publishing Plc. Esping-Andersen, Gøsta. 1999. Social foundations of postindustrial economies. New York: Oxford University Press. Estevez-Abe, M., T. Iversen, and D. Soskice. 2001. Social protection and the formation of skills: A reinterpretation of the welfare state. In Varieties of capitalism: The institutional foundations of comparative advantage, 145–183. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Etzerodt, S.F. 2021. Explaining economic growth in advanced capitalist democracies: Varieties of capitalism and welfare production regimes. Comparative European Politics 19 (4): 471–493. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1057/ s41295- 021- 00242-9. Fang, Zhenbang. 2005. The historical evolution of human resource management in Korean enterprises. Human Resources Development of China (3): 79–82. https:// doi. org/ 10. 16471/j. cnki. 11- 2822/c. 2005. 03. 021 (in Chinese). Grinberg, N. 2014. From miracle to crisis and back: The political economy of South Korean long-term development. Journal of Contemporary Asia 44 (4): 711–734. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1080/ 00472 336. 2014. 883421. Han, Keqing, Bingche Jin, and Dongfang Wang. 2011. A comparison of Chinese and Korean social policies under the east Asian welfare model. Comparative Economic & Social Systems (3): 41–52 (in Chinese). He, Qing. 2000. The knowledge economy and Japan’s economic recession. Contemporary Economy of Japan (6): 12–15. https:// doi. org/ 10. 16123/j. cnki. issn. 1000- 355x. 2000. 06. 003 (in Chinese). Hong, Sung-Dae, and Chul-Ju Kim. 2005. The study on transformation of family structure and orientation of family welfare in Korea. The Review of Korean Studies 8 (4): 187–208. Huang, Guizhen. 2010. The development of welfare capitalism in East Asia: The case of Japan, Korea and Taiwan. Journal of Public Administration (6): 7–30 (in Chinese). Huang, Jian. 1997. New trends in the development of Korean firms’ strategy. The Journal of World Economy (2): 57–58 (in Chinese). HUAWEI. 2021. Huawei unveils seven innovations in digital infrastructure, creating more value for customers and part- ners. Official website of HUAWEI. https:// www. huawei. com/ en/ news/ 2021/9/ huawei- conne ct- 2021- david- wang- seven- innov ations. Accessed 25 Mar 2022. Jacobs, David. 2000. Low public expenditures on social welfare: Do east Asian countries have a secret? International Journal of Social Welfare 9 (1): 2–16. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1111/ 1468- 2397. 00104. Jiang, Dayang, and Yingchao Yang. 2013. The evolution of Korea’s foreign economic strategy in the postwar period and its evaluation. Contemporary Economic Management (10): 72–78. https:// doi. org/ 10. 13253/j. cnki. ddjjgl. 2013. 10. 014 (in Chinese). Jin, Bingche, and Nanxi Du. 2020. A study on the change of family welfare policy in Korea in the context of low fertility crisis. Chinese Social Security Review (2): 117–130 (in Chinese). Jin, Fengde. 1986. A re-examination of the post-war Japanese economic development model- did Japan pursue an export-oriented strategy from the post-war period to the mid-1960s? Japanese Studies (6): 1–8+32 (in Chinese). Jung, In-Young. 2007. A comparative study of social assistance schemes in Korea and eight OECD countries. Social Wel- fare Policy 31: 7–33. https:// doi. org/ 10. 15855/ swp. 2007. 31.7. Kobayashi, H. 2014. The future of the public assistance reform in Japan: Workfare versus basic income? In Basic income in Japan: Prospects for a radical idea in a transforming welfare state, 83–99. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Koo, H. 1984. The political economy of income distribution in South Korea: The impact of the state’s industrialization poli- cies. World Development 12 (10): 1029–1037. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1016/ 0305- 750X(84) 90028-7. Kuang, Zengjie. 2013. Taiwan’s experience in transforming and upgrading processing trade and its implications. Reform of Economic System (4): 110–114 (in Chinese). M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 23 of 25 Kwon, Soonmee. 2005. Political systems, industrial development strategies, and welfare system: Comparing Japan, Taiwan and Korea during industrial period. 사회과학논집 36: 121–146. Lee, S.S.Y. 2016. Institutional legacy of state corporatism in de-industrial labour markets: A comparative study of Japan, South Korea and Taiwan. Socio-Economic Review 14 (1): 73–95. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1093/ ser/ mwv029. Lee, S.Y.S. 2011. The evolution of welfare production regimes in East Asia: A comparative study of Korea, Japan, and Taiwan. Korean Journal of Policy Studies 26 (1): 49–75. Li, Faxian, and Wei Zhao. 2008. A study of the changing attitudes of Taiwan’s trade unions in the face of privatization poli- cies – Taiwan’s trade unions since the 1980s. Taiwan Research Journal (3): 24–30 (in Chinese). Li, Xiangwen. 1998. The social security system in Korea. Journal of Graduate School of Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (1): 65–73 (in Chinese). Li, Yue. 2012. Technological innovation, development stages and strategic choices in science and technology: The exam- ple of Taiwan’s “Late-stage” science and technology development strategy. Economic Geography (6): 92–97. https:// doi. org/ 10. 15957/j. cnki. jjdl. 2012. 06. 015 (in Chinese). Li, Zhengfeng. 2000. The development of science and technology policy in Taiwan and its new tendency. Journal of Tsin- ghua University (Philosophy and Social Sciences) (2): 40–45. https:// doi. org/ 10. 13613/j. cnki. qhdz. 000737 (in Chinese). Lin, Benchu, and Ying Feng. 1999. Causes and treatment of unemployment problems in China and Korea. Reform of Economic System (S2): 112–115 (in Chinese). Lin, Changhua. 2002. An analysis of the current unemployment problem in Taiwan. Taiwan Research Journal (4): 51–55 (in Chinese). Liu, Guangwei. 2000. Korea’s technological innovation strategy and the impact on its economic recovery. Northeast Asia Forum 1: 27–29. https:// doi. org/ 10. 13654/j. cnki. naf. 2000. 01. 011 (in Chinese). Liu, Hongzhong, and Shuai Zhou. 2016. The historical evolution and inspiration of Korea’s foreign economic strategy. Frontiers (10): 22–27. https:// doi. org/ 10. 16619/j. cnki. rmltx sqy. 2016. 10. 003 (in Chinese). Liu, Wen. 2012. Comparison of trade union development in Japan and Korea and its implications. Northeast Asia Forum (2): 35–46 (in Chinese). Liu, Wen, and Jing Wang. 2011. Comparison of China, Japan and Korea’s economic development approaches and its implication. Shandong Social Sciences (7): 99–104. https:// doi. org/ 10. 14112/j. cnki. 37- 1053/c. 2011. 07. 036 (in Chinese). Liu, Xiangli. 2016a. A study on the relationship between skills and competitiveness of Japanese firms. Contemporary Economy of Japan (6): 68–79. https:// doi. org/ 10. 16123/j. cnki. issn. 1000- 355x. 2016. 06. 006 (in Chinese). Liu, Xiaochang. 2014. The development of welfare regimes in South Korea and Taiwan. Dongjiang Journal 31 (2): 19–24 (in Chinese). Liu, Xiaoyan. 2016b. Recovering the family: Reconstructing the social foundation of modern nation-building. Journal of Shanghai University (Social Sciences Edition) (6): 86–97 (in Chinese). Liu, Yan. 2005. Japan’s strategic transition to a knowledge-based economy. Statistical Research (3): 69–73. https:// doi. org/ 10. 19343/j. cnki. 11- 1302/c. 2005. 03. 016 (in Chinese). Lou, Suping, and Dianli Wang. 2016. Changes in East Asian familism in the context of aging - A case study of welfare poli- cies for the elderly in Japan and Korea. Journal of Public Administration (4): 88–103+207-208 (in Chinese). Luo, Hongguang. 2013. ‘Family welfare’ culture and the construction of welfare system in China. Sociological Studies (3): 145–161+244. https:// doi. org/ 10. 19934/j. cnki. shxyj. 2013. 03. 008 (in Chinese). Lv, Shoujun. 2011. The new changes in labor relations in Japan and its implications for China - A study based on the institutional theory of the French School of Regulation. Teaching and Research (11): 46–54 (in Chinese). Lv, Xuejing. 2016. Recent reforms of Japan’s social assistance system and its implications for China. Journal of Soochow University (Philosophy & Social Science Edition) (3): 45–50. https:// doi. org/ 10. 19563/j. cnki. sdzs. 2016. 03. 007 (in Chinese). Ma, Chunhua. 2017. Family change and family policy reconfiguration in contemporary Japan: Intergenerational redistri- bution of public resources. Journal of Social Development (3): 69–97+243 (in Chinese). Meng, Ke. 2021. Comparative institutional advantage in shared prosperity: A comparative social policy research agenda. In Paper presented at the 16th International Symposium of Social Policy, Nanjing, November 13–14, 2021. Ministry of Education, The People’s Republic of China. 2018. Modern apprenticeships ‘with Chinese characteristics’. The People’s Republic of China: Official website of Ministry of Education http:// en. moe. gov. cn/ Speci als/ Speci als_ 40th/ Frame work/ 201805/ t2018 0531_ 337947. html. Accessed 25 Mar 2022. Ministry of Human Resources and Social Security of the People’s Republic of China. 2020. China’s social security. Beijing: China Labor & Social Security Publishing House. Morikawa, M. 2010. Labor unions and productivity: An empirical analysis using Japanese firm-level data. Labour Econom- ics 17 (6): 1030–1037. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1016/j. labeco. 2010. 02. 009. Peng, Ito. 2002. Gender and welfare state restructuring in Japan. In Discovering the welfare state in East Asia, 39–62. Lon- don: Praeger. Peng, Wenbing. 2000. A review of social security system ideas in post-war Japan. Population Journal (2): 19–23. https:// doi. org/ 10. 16405/j. cnki. 1004- 129x. 2000. 02. 004 (in Chinese). Ping, Liqun, Cong Lin, and Miaomiao Liu. 2008. Changes in Japanese government policies to support corporate human resource development and its implications for China. Northeast Asia Forum (4): 73–78. https:// doi. org/ 10. 13654/j. cnki. naf. 2008. 04. 018 (in Chinese). Popa, M. 2021. Political machines and the institutional background of economic miracles. Government and Opposition 56 (2): 345–364. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1017/ gov. 2019. 33. Qi, Zhanyong, and Jiaxin Wang. 2018. The development and evolution of the Japanese vocational education system and its basic features. Journal of Hebei Normal University (Educational Science) (1): 73–78. https:// doi. org/ 10. 13763/j. cnki. jhebnu. ese. 2018. 01. 012 (in Chinese). Qian, Wenhao. 1995. An analysis of Japanese firms’ business strategy portfolio optimization. World Economy Studies (2): 52–54 (in Chinese). Ren, Wenxia. 1988. Strategies for economic development in postwar Japan. Contemporary Economy of Japan (6): 1–4 (in Chinese). Meng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 24 of 25 Rhee, Jong-Chan. 2004. The political management of state-led industrial adjustment: The Japanese and French cases during the period of high economic growth. International Area Studies Review 8 (1): 152–182. Ringen, Stein, Huck-ju Kwon, Ilcheon Yi, Taekyoon Kim, and Jooha Lee. 2012. Social welfare, effective governance and development- The case of South Korea. Journal of Public Administration (4): 77–92+180 (in Chinese). Rose, Richard, and Rei Shiratori. 1986. The welfare state east and west. New York: Oxford University Press. Sang, Fengping. 2012. Japan’s experience of industrial development to promote vocational education and its lessons. Educational Research (6): 150–154 (in Chinese). Shang, Chengyi. 1997. Vocational training in Korean enterprises and companies. Studies in Foreign Education (2): 43–46 (in Chinese). Shen, Qiu. 2016. The development process of family policy in Japan and Korea and its implications for China. Study and Practice (9): 114–122. https:// doi. org/ 10. 19624/j. cnki. cn42- 1005/c. 2016. 09. 015 (in Chinese). Shin, I., E. Yamamura, and H. Kim. 2012. The cubic form hypothesis and the flying geese pattern hypothesis of income distribution: The case of Korea. Theoretical and Empirical Researches in Urban Management 7 (3): 5–23 https:// www. jstor. org/ stable/ 24873 323. Shizume, M., M. Kato, and R. Matsuda. 2021. A corporate-centred conservative welfare regime: Three-layered protection in Japan. Journal of Asian Public Policy 14 (1): 110–133. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1080/ 17516 234. 2020. 18298 34. Song, Binwen, and Jianmin Wang. 2003. The evolution of the employment security system and unemployment insurance system in Taiwan, China. Population Journal (3): 36–39. https:// doi. org/ 10. 16405/j. cnki. 1004- 129x. 2003. 03. 007 (in Chinese). Song, Weiming. 1998. Characteristics of Korean firms’ technological innovation strategies. China Industrial Economics 1(7): 73–76. https:// doi. org/ 10. 19581/j. cnki. ciejo urnal. 1998. 07. 014 (in Chinese). State Post Bureau of The People’s Republic of China. 2021. Opinions on the protection of the legitimate rights and interests of courier groups. Official website of State Post Bureau of The People’s Republic of China http:// www. spb. gov. cn/ gjyzj/ c1000 09/ c1000 12/ 202107/ 3a4d5 96b56 1b468 9ad85 0d56a 4a237 a7. shtml. Accessed 25 Mar 2022 (in Chinese). Sun, Min. 2011. Taiwan’s social welfare system, its experience and inspiration. Contemporary World and Socialism (4): 153–157. https:// doi. org/ 10. 16502/j. cnki. 11- 3404/d. 2011. 04. 028 (in Chinese). The State Council Information Office of the People’s Republic of China. 2022. The Ministry of Commerce held a special press conference on ‘guidance on the high-quality implementation of RCEP’. Official website of The State Council Information Office of the People’s Republic of China http:// www. scio. gov. cn/ xwfbh/ gbwxw fbh/ xwfbh/ swb/ Docum ent/ 17197 55/ 17197 55. htm. Accessed 25 Mar 2022 (in Chinese). The State Council, The People’s Republic of China. 2014. Decision of the State Council on accelerating the development of modern vocational education. Official website of The State Council, The People’s Republic of China http:// www. gov. cn/ zheng ce/ conte nt/ 2014- 06/ 22/ conte nt_ 8901. htm. Accessed 25 Mar 2022 (in Chinese). Titmuss, Richard. 2001. The social division of welfare: Some reflections on the search for equity. In Welfare and wellbeing: Richard Titmuss’s contribution to social policy, 59–70. Bristol: Policy Press. Wang, H.S. 2015. Familialisation effects of the state welfare: Focused on the National Health Insurances in S. Korea and Taiwan. Asia Pacific Journal of Social Work and Development 25 (1): 29–41. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1080/ 02185 385. 2014. Wang, Hui. 2017. A review of research on low-skill balance. Human Resources Development of China (2): 137–144. https:// doi. org/ 10. 16471/j. cnki. 11- 2822/c. 2017. 02. 016 (in Chinese). Wang, Jianmin. 2000. A preliminary study of the employment security system and unemployment protection in Taiwan. Taiwan Studies (2): 29–37 (in Chinese). Wang, Xiaoling. 2009. Labor-management relations in Korea: From confrontation to negotiation. Journal of Contemporary Asia-Pacific Studies (4): 138–160+137 (in Chinese). Wedeman, A. 1997. Looters, rent-scrapers, and dividend-collectors: Corruption and growth in Zaire, South Korea, and the Philippines. The Journal of Developing Areas 31 (4): 457–478 https:// www. jstor. org/ stable/ 41927 13. Wu, Yongping. 2005. A political explanation of economic growth: State survival, bureaucratic politics, and private enterprises in the making of Taiwan’s economy, 1950–1985. Cambridge: Harvard University Asia Center. Wu, Yuanmin. 2011. Characteristics and insights of human resource management in Korean enterprises. Science Technol- ogy and Industry (1): 91–94 (in Chinese). Xi, Jinping. 2022. Making solid progress toward common prosperity. QIUSHI http:// en. qsthe ory. cn/ 2022- 01/ 18/c_ 699346. htm. Accessed 25 Mar 2022. Xu, Weidong, and Zhengping Li. 1998. The legal system of unemployment insurance in Japan. Contemporary Law Review (3): 37–39 (in Chinese). Yamamoto, D. 2012. Geographical political economy of regional inequality in postwar Japan. ICES working paper, No. 167. https:// d1wqt xts1x zle7. cloud front. net/ 56739 823/ 0B44B C76- 3752- 4316- A604- 15C61 B9E70 7C- with- cover- page- v2. pdf? Expir es= 16483 02610 & Signa ture= V2B6K 4is8p 59C3s umDt2J- QLpqz 3Ts6j J7c0Y Abt0V ~hZ8zH BCRXf cF9uj 3EEck RwD3N sCJtI U490B hDkZQ 9IkvA vDvHZ otkbo Myrjo z4ina Ua2Fl SNbyf- KWVaC 0nPZp wGPJu qbzuY SXnYm V3JTZ IW3uk 0fJNQ lQhyq 6cM0p iwR20 yZSj9 Bthsu nxeIB PyTlA tbSTn GDsWv PuWv~WfqVy 8CXL9 JnVsK XrAtW O75vx u6aFn ~0S6Du 0CzTV tj~SM6H3 k6TvW BcYKL 06U1N XLJL~mjAe5 YQoDc y~jylXi mBfM- VbpKC bYLU~pXsAu Kly3b Weout H05kR vKunD ZnGdZ jw__ & Key- Pair- Id= APKAJ LOHF5 GGSLR BV4ZA. Yan, Shimei. 1997. The current situation of women’s social status and its causes in Taiwan. Journal of Zhejiang University (Humanities and Social Sciences) (2): 58–63 (in Chinese). Yan, Shimei. 2002. Problems, counseling strategies and implications for technological advancement of SMEs in Taiwan. Science & Technology Progress and Policy (1): 75–76 (in Chinese). Yang, Lingling. 2008. The process, characteristics and causes of the establishment of the Korean social security system. Scientific Socialism (6): 159–161 (in Chinese). Yang, Lixian. 1997. An examination of the situation of labor-management relations in Taiwan since the restoration (con- tinued). Taiwan Studies (2): 39–83 (in Chinese). M eng and Zhong Asian Review of Political Economy (2022) 1:7 Page 25 of 25 Yang, Y., and T.M. Greaney. 2017. Economic growth and income inequality in the Asia-Pacific region: A comparative study of China, Japan, South Korea, and the United States. Journal of Asian Economics (48): 6–22. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1016/j. asieco. 2016. 10. 008. Zhang, Jifeng. 2000. Structural characteristics of unemployment and employment mechanisms in postwar Japan. Japa- nese Studies (4): 65–79 (in Chinese). Zhang, Shihong. 2004. The choice of Taiwan’s export-oriented industrialization strategy and the reasons for its successful implementation. Taiwan Research Journal (3): 23–29+68 (in Chinese). Zhang, Xiaofeng. 2001. The reform and development of vocational and technical education in Taiwan and its inspiration to us. Vocational and Technical Education (25): 52–55 (in Chinese). Zhang, Zhanli. 2011. The role of the Korean employment insurance system on the labor market and its insights - An analysis based on the two economic crises in 1997 and 2008. Southwest Finance (12): 55–59 (in Chinese). Zhao, Shuming, and Zhenqiu Tan. 1996. Human resource management and development in Korean companies. World Economics and Politics (4): 42–45 (in Chinese). Zhao, Shuming, and Wei Zhao. 2006. A comparative study of labor relations management in the United States, Germany and Japan. Foreign Economics & Management (1): 17–22+29. https:// doi. org/ 10. 16538/j. cnki. fem. 2006. 01. 003 (in Chinese). Zhao, Yongsheng. 2009. A review of the Japanese social assistance system under familism. Japanese Studies (5): 98–111+158-159 (in Chinese). Zhao, Zengyao. 2000. Japan’s labor market system and the challenges and new changes it faces. World Economics and Politics (12): 57–60 (in Chinese). Zou, Yanhui. 2012. The social security administrative system in Taiwan. Lanzhou Academic Journal (4): 141–145 (in Chinese). Publisher’s Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Asian Review of Political Economy – Springer Journals
Published: Oct 18, 2022
Keywords: Welfare production regime; Shared prosperity; Economic growth; Income distribution
You can share this free article with as many people as you like with the url below! We hope you enjoy this feature!
Read and print from thousands of top scholarly journals.
Already have an account? Log in
Bookmark this article. You can see your Bookmarks on your DeepDyve Library.
To save an article, log in first, or sign up for a DeepDyve account if you don’t already have one.
Copy and paste the desired citation format or use the link below to download a file formatted for EndNote
Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
All DeepDyve websites use cookies to improve your online experience. They were placed on your computer when you launched this website. You can change your cookie settings through your browser.